Demurrage currency,[a] also known as depreciating money[2]: 7 or stamp scrip in its paper money form,[3] is a type of money that is designed to gradually lose purchasing power at a flat constant rate.[b] Unlike traditional money, demurrage is designed to only be a temporary store of value. Demurrage money functions primarily as a medium of exchange and unit of account.[4][2]: 16 In some cases, demurrage currencies have been employed as emergency currencies, intended to keep the circular flow of income running throughout the economy during recessions and times of war, due to their faster circulation velocities.[2]: 16–17 [5]: 8
Demurrage is sometimes cited as economically advantageous, usually in the context of complementary currency systems. The German-Argentine economist, Silvio Gesell, advocated for demurrage currency as part of the Freiwirtschaft economic system. He referred to demurrage as Freigeld 'free money' — "free" because it would be freed from hoarding and interest.[6][4] Gesell theorized that Freigeld would increase the velocity of money, eliminate inflation, reduce unemployment, create an interest-free economy, and lead to fewer recessions.[5]: 2 [4]
Theory
The functions of money
While demurrage carrying costs[b] are a natural feature of commodity money, demurrage has at various times been deliberately incorporated into currency systems as a disincentive to hoard money and to achieve more efficient allocation of capital in society, thus creating demurrage currency.
Freiwirtschaft economists propose that the function of money as a store of value is incompatible with its function as a medium of exchange for maximum economic efficiency. In The Natural Economic Order, Gesell wrote: "The power of money to effect exchanges, its technical quality from the mercantile standpoint, is in inverse proportion to its technical quality from the banking standpoint."[7] This implies that money that is great for storing wealth, such as hard currency, is bad for functioning as a medium of exchange,[8] even though the latter function was the prime reason why money was created in the first place. Since demurrage currency is deliberately designed to be bad at storing value, it is therefore great at functioning as a medium of exchange,[9] which Gesell believed to be the only legitimate function of money.[10][11]
"Only money that goes out of date like a newspaper, rots like potatoes, rusts like iron, evaporates like ether, is capable of standing the test as an instrument for the exchange of potatoes, newspapers, iron and ether. For such money is not preferred to goods either by the purchaser or the seller. We then part with our goods for money only because we need the money as a means of exchange, not because we expect an advantage from possession of the money. So we must make money worse as a commodity if we wish to make it better as a medium of exchange."[9]
— Silvio Gesell, The Natural Economic Order
Gresham's law that "bad money drives out good" suggests that demurrage currency would suffer more rapid circulation than competing forms of currency. This led some such as Silvio Gesell to propose demurrage as a means of increasing both the velocity of money and overall economic activity. In real-life experiments during the early-to-mid 1900s, demurrage on money was demonstrated to significantly increase the velocity of money in circulation, even incentivizing people to pay their taxes in advance.[12]
Preventing recessions
One of the most important differences between demurrage and inflation is how they affect economic recessions differently:[13]
- Inflation is defined as "a general rise in prices".
- During recessions, prices tend to fall.
- When prices fall and we can expect them to continue falling, commerce falls too. People avoid buying commodities sooner when they expect that they can buy them cheaper later.
- Recessions thus face a game theory problem: society wants to increase commerce, but nobody with hoardable money wants to increase commerce if prices will continue to fall.
- If prices are falling, then there is no inflation, by definition.
- If there is no inflation, then there are no penalties for withholding money from circulation during a recession.
- Thus, holders of money are rewarded for withholding their money from circulation during periods of falling prices.
- This makes it difficult to increase circulation and end the recession.
By contrast, demurrage currency would encourage people to keep commerce going during recessions, unlike inflation. If money continues to lose purchasing power (even at a slow rate), then people will use it sooner rather than later.[14] Gesell proposed that money should have a demurrage rate 5.2% per year, or 0.1% per week, but he also believed that real-world experimentation would probably be necessary to figure out the optimal rate.[9]
In some cases, demurrage currencies have been employed as emergency currencies, intended to keep the circular flow of income running throughout the economy during recessions and times of war, due to their faster circulation velocities.[2]: 16–17 [5]: 8
Other differences between demurrage and inflation
Inflation and demurrage both tend to reduce the liquid savings over time, but there are many crucial differences between the two. Unlike inflation, demurrage gradually reduces only the value of currency held, not on newly issued money, money placed into a bank (from the lender's perspective), nor money that will be claimed or issued in the future.[5]: 15–16 In fact, demurrage would increase the value of claims to future money like stocks and bonds, since they would become a more reliable way to store wealth, due to the penalty on holding cash.[5]: 16 Inflation also increases prices across the consumer price index, whereas demurrage does not.
Inflation also benefits borrowers at the expense of lenders, whereas demurrage does not. The effect of demurrage on borrowers depends on what they do with the money. If they spend it (either for consumption or investment), they do not bear the cost of demurrage. If borrowers hold onto the money, they would lose due to demurrage. People are thus strongly disincentivized to borrow demurrage money without spending it.
The rate of inflation usually fluctuates, and inflation may devalue currency in a variety of ways, so inflation is not easy to predict.[15][16] By contrast, the depreciation rate of demurrage currency would stay at a fixed rate set by the government, thus leading to a more stable and predictable economy with lower prices.[5]: 16
Freiwirtschaft economists theorize that demurrage currency could eliminate both inflation and deflation. There tends to be some interest cost that is built into the goods and services that consumers tend to purchase,[5]: 4 so if demurrage currency eliminates interest rates, then prices are less likely to increase. Demurrage would also naturally cause the money supply to decrease, thus causing deflation. If a central bank issues and monitors demurrage currency as Gesell originally proposed, then it could replace all the money that disappears due to demurrage by printing money at a similar rate.[6] The money printing could create just enough inflation to cancel out the natural deflation of demurrage, thus achieving an inflation target of 0%.[17]
Interest rates, lending, and borrowing
Some regard demurrage as a negative interest rate policy, but they have different effects. Under demurrage currency, hoarding money becomes impossible because the face-value of money depreciates regularly. This forces the circulation of money.[18] By contrast, it is possible to hoard money on negative interests, since the face-value of money is constant and people can use their money as a means of saving. For example, Japan's negative interest rates drove up the sales of safes and strongboxes.[19]
Negative interest rates tend to discourage people from storing their money in banks, in order to avoid having their money depreciate in value. For this reason, it can be difficult to decrease the money supply and/or cause deflation, so some aspects of monetary policy could theoretically become ineffective at low interest rates.[3] Some economists have expressed interest in demurrage currency as a way to avoid this problem and effectively turn interest rates negative.[4][20][3]
When the medium of exchange is scarce, traders will pay to rent it (interest), which acts as an impedance to trade. In stable or deflationary environments, interest is a net transfer of wealth from debtor to creditor. Under inflationary environments, interest is a net transfer of wealth from creditor to the debtor. Demurrage currency aims to end both of these cases.
If the liquidity preference theory of interest rates is correct, then interest rates would disappear when money cannot be used as a long-term store of value, so demurrage money would theoretically have no interest rates. Under a demurrage monetary system, banks would be incentivized to loan money to avoid paying demurrage fees.[c] This new incentive would lead to a further incentive for bankers to lend demurrage money without charging interest rates, in order to reduce the disincentives for borrowers to borrow demurrage money.[6][4] The result would be an interest-free economy.
Borrowers would also be incentivized to use the demurrage money as soon as possible before the purchasing power decreases due to demurrage. Since demurrage money would theoretically increase the velocity of money, eliminate interest rates, and lower the opportunity costs to borrowing credit, demurrage money could theoretically lead to greater economic efficiency and prosperity.[22]
For long-term investment financing, demurrage currency affects the dynamics of net present value (NPV) calculations. Demurrage in a currency system reduces discount rates, and thus increases the present value of a long-term investment, and thus gives an incentive for such investments.[23]
Economic and environmental sustainability
Freiwirtschaft economist Felix Fuders argues that the growth imperative of modern economies is caused by interest burdens on debt, inflation, and opportunity costs created by the existence of interest.[24] Fuders believes that the growth imperative has harmful environmental and social consequences.[25] Fuders concludes that it is impossible to meaningfully address the problem of unsustainable growth or fulfill the sustainable development goals proposed by the United Nations without completely overhauling the monetary system in favor of demurrage currency.[26]
Bernard Lietaer and Dieter Suhr have also argued that the existence of interest has negative impacts on resource consumption and the environment. As an example, Lietaer wrote: "When it pays more to cut a tree, sell the wood and let the proceeds earn interest than simply let the tree grow, it is predictable that "economic pressures" will be felt to cut more trees than is optimal from an ecological viewpoint. Stamp Scrip would reverse that process."[5]: 5 [27]
Proceeds of the system
In some instances, the demurrage fee is charged by some sort of central authority, and is paid into a fund. The application of this fund varies widely among both historical and proposed systems. In some cases, it is used to pay the costs of administering the tax. If the currency in question is run by the government, the demurrage fee can contribute to general tax revenue.
In Gesell's proposed system, the individual owners of Freigeld would pay the demurrage fee for the stamps to the government, thus reducing the amount of other taxes that a government would have to collect.[6] If individuals do not want to pay the demurrage fees, they could deposit their money into a bank. The bank would become responsible for paying for the stamp fees, and the money would retain its full value from the depositor's perspective. Bank would thus be incentivized to loan the money in order to pass the holding expense onto others and avoid paying for the stamps, which would guarantee that plenty of money would be available for lending in the economy. Gesell believed that banks would loan until their interest rates eventually fall to zero. Banks would collect only a small risk premium and an administration fee, without any need to adjust for inflation or deflation.[6]
In mutual credit systems, all positive accounts, or those over a credit threshold, are debited the demurrage fee if there is no trading (purchasing) after a certain period (e.g. a month or year after the last purchase). The fee typically accrues to the administration account and thus adds to the common credit pool.
Critical analysis
British economist John Maynard Keynes contended that Gesell's proposed demurrage fees could be evaded by the use of more liquid competing forms of money and that inflation was therefore a preferable method to achieve economic stimulation.[28] However, Scottish economist Ahmed Anwar argues that Keynes' objection to demurrage currency is flawed and contrary to Gresham's law.[29]
One of the main barriers to the success of any demurrage currency is establishing it as a trusted medium of exchange. People generally only accept payments in a currency when they believe that it will be accepted in future exchanges. When businesses do not accept demurrage money, workers usually refuse to receive it as payment.[3] Additionally, Jérôme Blanc argues that past experiments on demurrage currency relied heavily on both a distrust in the value of conventional money, as well as trust among a local community. Although past experiments have worked successfully in small towns, they may not be as effective across an entire country, unless there is a way to ensure that trust in demurrage currency can scale with the size of the population that uses it.[30][2]: 12
None of the localities that have used demurrage currency in the past and present have fully implemented all three of the main proposals of Gesell's Freiwirtschaft. Since only the Freigeld aspect of the theory and proposal has been tested, the Freiland and Freihandel aspects of the theory would also need to be implemented simultaneously, in order to observe how a Freiwirtschaft economy would work as a whole.[31]
According to economist Dirk Löhr , while demurrage currency has successfully worked on local scales in the past and present, and while freiland reform is possible without freigeld reform, there is an economic consensus that successful large-scale freigeld monetary reform will not be possible without freiland reform.[32] The reason is that if money can no longer be used as a long-term store of wealth, then most people would shift to storing their wealth within land instead. If land reform is unfeasible for any reason, then large scale freigeld reform will be unlikely to have its intended effects.[32]
Professors Nikolaus Läufer and Gerhard Rösl argued that demurrage currencies can only increase economic activity temporarily.[33] They believe that although the velocity of money would increase in the short-term, the total amount in circulation would gradually decrease, since demurrage currencies lose value over time. The lengthy use of demurrage currencies would thus ultimately lead to a decline in economic activity and economic instability.[34][clarification needed] However, Gesell supported allowing a monetary authority to monitor the money supply. If the amount of money in circulation falls too much, the monetary authorty would print more money.[6]
Gesell believed that Freiwirtschaft would create Darwinian natural selection in the economy: "Free competition would favor the efficient and lead to their increased propagation."[6] Marxists such as the academic Elmar Altvater described Freigeld as a "Social Darwinist concept" and criticized its past supporters for trying to ally with the Nazi Party, even though the Nazis ignored their ideas.[35] Werner Onken replied to this accusation that the theory of evolution was new at that time and existed in contrast to the dogmas of Christianity above all. Onken wrote that Gesell did not represent a "struggle of the strongest against the weaker", as he instead advocated "to create the conditions for a just distribution of income and wealth".[36]
History
Pre-modern usage
Bernard Lietaer documents in his book Mysterium Geld the use of demurrage currency systems in Europe's High Middle Ages' bracteate systems and Ancient Egypt's ostraka – dated receipts for the storage of grain – and credits these currency systems with the prosperity of those societies.[5]: 5–6 [37] One notable example of demurrage is the founder of the Mark of Brandenburg, Albert the Bear.[38]
The Islamic system of zakat sometimes works as a form of demurrage tax, but not always since it applies to assets generally, not currency specifically. Zakat on wealth is based on the value of all of one's possessions.[39][40] It is customarily 2.5% (or 1⁄40)[41] of a Muslim's total savings and wealth above a minimum amount known as nisab each lunar year,[42] but Islamic scholars differ on how much nisab is and other aspects of zakat.[42] Today, in most Muslim-majority countries, zakat contributions are voluntary, while in Libya, Malaysia, Pakistan, Saudi Arabia, Sudan and Yemen, zakat is mandated and collected by the state (as of 2015).[43][44]
Guernsey experiment of 1815
In 1815, there was a money experiment on Guernsey in the British Channel Islands. The consequences of the Napoleonic Wars were noticeable throughout Europe, including on this island. The islanders produced food far beyond its own needs, but the collected taxes and interest payments to London banks finally brought payments to a halt. The incumbent governor of Guernsey, Daniel de Lisle Brock, proposed the construction of a market hall for 4000 pounds sterling to give the economy a new impetus. These 4000 pounds were printed and put into circulation as a complementary currency. After five years, the hall had fully amortized, which means that it had fully earned its depreciation and the 4000 pounds, which had now been in circulation on the whole of the island and had caused all kinds of revenues, were again available to the investor of the market hall, and were no longer needed and burned. According to this principle, several building projects with self-printed and later again destroyed building projects were realized one after the other. However, by 1835, the intervention of foreign banks and a reduced money supply caused the economy to come to a standstill again. Some supporters of Freiwirtschaft, including Hermann Benjes , regard the "Mirakel of Guernsey" as a precursor to demurrage money,[45] after Silvio Gesell, who wrote an article about the experiment.[46] The Guernsey pound is still used today.[5]: 7
1890s and early 1900s
The application of deliberate demurrage rates on currency was first theorized to have economic benefits by Silvio Gesell in the 1890s. Gesell first started thinking about the structural problems caused by the monetary system after the 1890 depression in Argentina hurt his business considerably. Gesell released his first theoretical writing on currency: The Reformation of the Monetary System as a Bridge to a Social State (German: Die Reformation des Münzwesens als Brücke zum sozialen Staat, 1891). He also wrote and published The Nerve of Things (Latin: Nervus rerum, 1891) and The nationalization of money (German: Die Verstaatlichung des Geldes, 1892). In 1916, Gesell later published his most famous work on demurrage, The Natural Economic Order.
After Gesell died in 1930, many localities were inspired his economic theories and tried using demurrage currencies to alleviate their local economies during the Great Depression.
The Great Depression
Europe
Schwanenkirchen, Bavaria was among the first towns ever to test Gesell's Freiwirtschaft proposals. In 1929, the owner of a bankrupt coal mine, Max Hebecker, decided to pay two-thirds of his workers' salaries in a currency known as the Wära, which was pegged to the Reichsmark. By 1931, the coal mine was restarted, the Wära was widely used in Schwanenkirchen and the local economy greatly improved, and the currency was used by over 2000 businesses from all over Germany. In November 1931, the German Central Bank outlawed the currency, and economic stagnation continued.[5]: 6

Demurrage-charged local currency was tested in the Austrian town of Wörgl between 1932 and 1934, as a tax collected for the benefit of the unemployed. Due to the local currency's success in reducing unemployment and increasing economic activity, at least 200 cities across Austria formed plans to mimic the currency system in Wörgl.[5]: 7 However, these plans were never realized since Austria's central bank Oesterreichische Nationalbank outlawed complementary currencies in the country on 1 September 1933, so that the federal government would maintain a monopoly on the country's currency and legal tender.[47][48]
In 1933, a National Committee of the Mutual Exchanges was formed in Nice, France, which created trade vouchers intended to circulate only between members, mainly traders. (The Committee's statutes appeared in the press on 12 September, the creation of the association being officially announced at the Olympic Day on 10 December of the same year). Under the ministry of Laval, the Banque de France intervened and declared the experiment illegal. After World War II, a jeweler by the name of Soriano, who participated in this experiment, gave his support for "the libre commune of Lignières-en-Berry".[49][50]
In August 1936, the city of Montoro issued what might have been the first demurrage currency in all of Spain. The local council printed a series of five-peseta bills, each with a depreciation table on one side. The value of bills decreased weekly. For example, a bill that was worth five pesetas on November 1 would be worth 4.50 pesetas on November 8. If the bills remained unused after twelve weeks, they would be only partially redeemable at the town hall. There were similar monetary experiments in Porcuna and other locations in Spain that were ruled by the Popular Front in Córdoba province in 1936-1937.[2]: 15
At the end of the Spanish Civil War, Francisco Franco's government confiscated and voided all Republican money, municipal coins, and local banknotes. Meanwhile, Franco decreed that all the municipal currencies issued by the winning national army could be exchanged at the Bank of Spain for the new Spanish currency (Order 5, Decree 27 August 1938 published on 17 September 1938). Despite being prohibited, many complementary currencies continued to circulate among the population as a medium of exchange for years after the Spanish Civil War (1939-1955).[2]: 15
North America
Local stamp scrip systems, many of which incorporated demurrage fees, were used in at least 450 cities during the Great Depression in the United States.[5]: 7 Most scrip was issued in late 1932 and early 1933 before Franklin Roosevelt succeeded the presidency, and when bank suspensions were the most frequent and widespread. The New Jersey, Ohio, Michigan, Indiana, North Dakota, Tennessee, and North Carolina state legislatures all passed laws allowing localities in their respective states to issue stamp scrip.[3][51] Iowa even went as far as to propose issuing statewide stamp scrip, but never enacted it.[52] Oregon planned to print $80 million of stamp scrip in 1933, but was stopped by the U.S. Treasury.[6] The experiments became so popular that the economist Irving Fisher decided to analyze them. Fisher criticized how most of the scrip that was used in the US was undated, since dated scrip would have been necessary to incentivize users to buy stamps for renewing the value of the scrip.[3] Fisher instead recommended issuing dated stamp scrip nationwide in his book Stamp Scrip, but President Roosevelt rejected Fisher's recommendations.[53][33]
Fisher composed the Bankhead-Pettengill bill that was introduced to Congress by Senator John H. Bankhead II of Alabama on February 17, 1933. Fisher proposed a nationwide issue of up to $1 billion in $1 dated stamp scrip as legal tender under the US Treasury, but the bill never came to a vote. Similar bills were subsequently proposed in Congress, but none succeeded.[3] In March 1933, President Franklin Roosevelt banned all further issues of stamp scrip out of fear that the federal government would lose its authority over the monetary system.[5]: 7 [2]: 12 which arguably prolonged the Great Depression.[citation needed]
In 1936, the Social Credit Party-led government in Alberta, Canada, introduced prosperity certificates in an attempt to alleviate the effects of the Great Depression, with holders having to affix to the back of a certificate a 1-cent stamp before the end of every week, for the certificate to maintain its validity.
Post World War II
The major central banks' post-World War II policy of steady monetary inflation as proposed by Keynes was influenced by Gesell's idea of demurrage currency,[28] but used inflation of the money supply rather than fees to increase the velocity of money in an attempt to expand the economy.
On 9 September 1950, the Free Social Party was founded in Germany with a platform based on Gesell's Freiwirtschaft theory. After a few name changes, it has been known as the Human Economics Party (German: Humanwirtschaftspartei) since 28 April 2001.[54]
Two brief experiments took place in Cher, France in 1956 and Charente-Maritime, France in 1957 respectively. Issued by an association under the term "vouchers" or "work vouchers", these demurrage currencies were abandoned in December 1958 following the adoption of an ordinance prohibiting "the issuance or putting into circulation of means of payment intended to replace or replace legal tender signs".[55]
Pierre Tournadre, a watchmaker, and Georges Lardeau, director of a cinema, who faced rural exodus and economic decline, declared on 26 April 1956 "the libre commune of Lignières-en-Berry". The demurrage money was issued in August 1956. As word of the experiment spread, the government started tabling a bill in December to try to ban the currencies. In June 1957, a judicial police investigation pressed no charges. The journal "Science et Vie" (Étienne Dugue, La monnaie accelerated, number 488, May 1958) noted that this experiment ended on 24 December 1958, due to the passage of ordinance 58-1298.[56][49]
The Great Recession
The Great Recession inspired many communities to establish local demurrage currencies. There are currently a handful of demurrage currencies that are still used today.[57]
In, Shaymuratovo, Bashkortostan, Russia, the town's declining agricultural enterprise implemented a demurrage currency in 2010, in the wake of the Great Recession. The government believed that this was a violation of labor laws and shut the currency down. The community tried to implement a demurrage currency once more, but this time as gift cards, instead of an official currency. People were paid their full salaries and rubles, but then could buy the new currency in the company stores and then buy goods with it. Overall, the experiment caused commodity turnover to increased dramatically. Productivity increased, arrears were paid off, and salaries increased. The surrounding region took notice and other businesses started to accept the currency, whether from the experiment or from the business climate improving in general. Although the goal of saving the business was achieved and the economy was stabilized, the government once again tried to stop the experiment multiple times, leading to its retirement after a few years.[58][59]
List of demurrage currencies
Current currencies

- Chiemgauer, a community currency in Bavaria, Germany, started in 2003.[60][61][62]
- Stroud pound, a community currency in Stroud, Gloucestershire, England, started in 2009. The Stroud pound was inspired by the Chiemgauer, and has a demurrage rate of 3% every six months.[57]
- Abeille, a community currency in Villeneuve-sur-Lot, France, started in 2010. To maintain an individual bill's validity, a stamp scrip corresponding to 2% of the banknote value must be paid every six months.[63]
- Occitan, a community currency in Languedoc-Roussillon, France, started in 2010. It is interest-free and designed to circulate faster.[64]
- Peanuts, a local currency that was created in Chiba Prefecture, Japan in February 1999 as a part of the Eco-Money Network.[65] Peanuts has a demurrage charge of 1% per month, and is used by over 600 participants, including local businesses, farmers, and individuals.[66]
- Freicoin, a crypto-currency that was developed by Mark Friedenbach and launched on 17 December 2012. Freicoin has a demurrage rate of ~4.9% per year, which discourages price speculation and theoretically makes Freicoin a superior medium of exchange, compared to Bitcoin.[27]
Defunct currencies
- Wära, a local currency used in Schwanenkirchen, Bavaria and later other German cities as one of the first free economy experiments. It was introduced by Hans Timm and Helmut Rödiger, who were followers of Silvio Gesell. It was introduced in 1926, and operated until it was shut down by the German Central Bank and the Reich Ministry of Finance.[5]: 6
- Wörgler Schwundgeld , the currency of the Wörgl Experiment. Began on 31 July 1932 and ended by Austria's central bank Oesterreichische Nationalbank on 1 September 1933.[47][48]
- Local currency "stamp scrip" experiments were conducted in several cities in the United States during the 1930s.[52][51][3] In March 1933, President Franklin Roosevelt banned all further issues of stamp scrip out of fear that the federal government would lose its authority over the monetary system.,[5]: 7 [2]: 12 which arguably prolonged the Great Depression.[citation needed]
- Prosperity certificate, a local currency in Alberta, Canada that existed in 1936.[67]
- WIR Bank, a bank founded by Swiss businessmen Werner Zimmermann and Paul Enz that circulated demurrage currency from 1936 to 1948.[68]
- Crédito, an Argentine interest-free[69] community currency, started on 1 May 1995 that lost most of its popularity in the early 2000s. Some variants of the Crédito that were used in the Argentinian barter clubs of the late 1990s and the early 2000s allegedly used demurrage.[citation needed] At its peak, the Crédito was used by a few million people.[65]
- E-gold, a private digital gold currency where there was a gold storage charge of 1% per annum. The demurrage associated with e-gold is arguably expended by the currency operator to help cover real storage costs.[citation needed] E-gold was launched in 1996, and suspended in 2009 due to legal issues.
- Renovatio Monetae was a monetary system during the High Middle Ages where coins had to be called back and exchanged for new coins regularly, about once or twice a year.[38][37]
- In Ancient Egypt, ostraka – dated receipts for the storage of grain – functioned as a demurrage currency.[38] Ostraka was used in Egypt until the end of the Ptolemaic Kingdom, after which it was forcefully replaced by Roman currency.[5]: 5–6
Proposed currencies
- A carry tax on currency was proposed by a Federal Reserve employee (Marvin Goodfriend) in 1999, to be implemented via magnetic strips on bills, deducting the carry tax upon deposit, the tax being based on how long the bill had been held.[70]
- Bernard Lietaer's terra is a commodity basket currency proposal similar to Keynes's bancor or L'Europa (The idea to establish a L'Europa – monnaie de la paix from early concepts presented in an article in the French newspaper Le Fédériste on 1 January 1933) and bearing a demurrage charge.[71][72]
Fictional currencies
- Michael Ende stated that he had the concept of demurrage currency in mind when writing his children's fantasy novel Momo.[73] Momo features a currency that revolves around time, which can be exchanged between people.
- A negative interest rate could be levied on existing paper currency in principle via a serial number lottery, such as randomly choosing a number 0 through 9 and declaring that notes whose serial number end in that digit are worthless, yielding an average 10% loss of paper cash holdings to hoarders; a drawn two-digit number could match the last two digits on the note for a 1% loss. This was proposed by an anonymous student of Greg Mankiw,[20] though it was more of a thought experiment than a genuine proposal.
See also
- Local exchange trading system
- Community Exchange System
- Eco-Pesa
- Sarafu-Credit
- Community-based economics
- Seigniorage
- The Future of Money
Notes
- ^ The etymology for demurrage currency comes from the concept of demurrage. In the shipping industry, "demurrage" refers to a charge that is assessed to the operator of a ship that fails to load or unload within the agreed upon timeframe. A ship that takes longer than it's supposed to unload to load or unload affects the ability of other ships to do likewise. Therefore a financial penalty is assessed to discourage such behavior. Demurrage money applies the same principle, but to money.[1]
- ^ a b In other contexts, demurrage may refer to the carrying cost associated with owning or holding currency over a given period, rather than the money itself. For commodity money such as spices, demurrage is the cost of storing and securing the spices. For paper currency, it can take the form of a periodic tax, such as a stamp tax, on currency holdings.
- ^ To be clear, the total interest rate typically consists of four components: pure (risk-free) interest, a risk premium, expected inflation or deflation, and administrative costs. In this context, the intended meaning is that demurrage money would theoretically have no pure interest rates, whereas the other three components of interest would remain. Banks would still be able to profit from loaning money under a demurrage monetary system, since they would be paid by the administrative costs component of the total interest rate.[21]
References
- ^ Sidman, Josh (3 April 2024). "Silvio Gesell: Beyond Capitalism vs Socialism" Class #6 (Video). Henry George School of Economics. Event occurs at 6:47. Retrieved 2 May 2025.
- ^ a b c d e f g h i Gomez, Georgina M; Prittwitz und Gaffron, Wilko von (2018). "The pervasiveness of monetary plurality in economic crisis and wars" (PDF). Erasmus University Rotterdam. International Institute of Social Studies of Erasmus University Rotterdam. Retrieved 25 April 2025.
- ^ a b c d e f g h Champ, Bruce (April 2008). "Stamp Scrip: Money People Paid To Use". Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Research Department. Retrieved 21 April 2025.
- ^ a b c d e Rosalsky, Greg (27 August 2019). "The 'Strange, Unduly Neglected Prophet'". NPR. Retrieved 25 April 2025.
- ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l m n o p q Lietaer, Bernard A. (July 1990). "A Strategy for a Convertible Currency" (PDF). ICIS Forum. 20 (3). International Center for Integrative Studies. Retrieved 4 May 2025.
- ^ a b c d e f g h Baynham, Jacob (14 November 2023). "What If Money Expired?". Noema Magazine. Berggruen Institute. Retrieved 26 April 2025.
- ^ Gesell, Silvio (1916). "Die natürliche Wirtschaftsordnung durch Freiland und Freigeld" [The Natural Economic Order/Part III/Chapter 10: The Supply of Money]. Translated by Pye, Philip. Bern, Switzerland. ISBN 9781610330442. Archived from the original on 17 March 2025. Retrieved 30 April 2025 – via The Anarchist Library.
{{cite web}}
: ISBN / Date incompatibility (help) - ^ Greco, Thomas H. (2001). Money: Understanding and Creating Alternatives to Legal Tender. White River Junction, Vt: Chelsea Green Publishing. ISBN 1-890132-37-3.
- ^ a b c Gesell, Silvio (1916). "Die natürliche Wirtschaftsordnung durch Freiland und Freigeld" [The Natural Economic Order/Part IV/Chapter 1: Free-Money]. Translated by Pye, Philip. Bern, Switzerland. ISBN 9781610330442. Archived from the original on 17 March 2025. Retrieved 30 April 2025 – via The Anarchist Library.
{{cite web}}
: ISBN / Date incompatibility (help) - ^ Gesell, Silvio (1916). "Die natürliche Wirtschaftsordnung durch Freiland und Freigeld" [The Natural Economic Order/Part IV/Free-Money, Or Money As It Should Be]. Translated by Pye, Philip. Bern, Switzerland. ISBN 9781610330442. Archived from the original on 17 March 2025. Retrieved 30 April 2025 – via The Anarchist Library.
{{cite web}}
: ISBN / Date incompatibility (help) - ^ Sidman, Josh (4 March 2024). "Silvio Gesell: Beyond Capitalism vs Socialism" Class #2 (Video). Henry George School of Economics. Event occurs at 29:00. Retrieved 30 April 2025.
- ^ Smith, Fred J. (2015). Quantum Money. CreateSpace Independent Publishing Platform. ISBN 978-1517264048.
- ^ Sidman, Josh (3 April 2024). "Silvio Gesell: Beyond Capitalism vs Socialism" Class #6 (Video). Henry George School of Economics. Event occurs at 9:56. Retrieved 2 May 2025.
- ^ Bozhya-Volya, Roman N.; Rybak, Alina S. (18 January 2019). "Why Should Money Lose Value With Time: Boosting Economy in the Era of E-Money" (PDF). Higher School of Economics. National Research University Higher School of Economics. Retrieved 2 May 2025.
- ^ Stock, James H.; Watson, Mark W. (February 2007). "Why Has U.S. Inflation Become Harder to Forecast?" (PDF). Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. 39 (1). Blackwell Publishing Limited. Retrieved 2 May 2025 – via Harvard University.
- ^ Mitchell, Bill (7 July 2010). "Modern monetary theory and inflation". William Mitchell - Modern Monetary Theory. Retrieved 23 May 2025.
- ^ Sidman, Josh (3 April 2024). "Silvio Gesell: Beyond Capitalism vs Socialism" Class #6 (Video). Henry George School of Economics. Event occurs at 15:18. Retrieved 23 May 2025.
- ^ Bershidsky, Leonid (3 July 2015). "'Neglected Prophet' of Economics Got It Right". Bloomberg. Retrieved 1 June 2017.
- ^ Shen, Lucinda (2016-02-23). "Japan's Negative Interest Rates Are Driving up Sales of Safes". Fortune. Retrieved 1 June 2017.
- ^ a b Mankiw, N. Gregory (18 April 2009). "It May Be Time for the Fed to Go Negative". The New York Times.
- ^ Sidman, Josh (11 March 2024). "Silvio Gesell: Beyond Capitalism vs Socialism" Class #3 (Video). Henry George School of Economics. Event occurs at 1:28. Retrieved 26 May 2025.
- ^ Sidman, Josh (25 March 2024). "Silvio Gesell: Beyond Capitalism vs Socialism" Class #5 (Video). Henry George School of Economics. Retrieved 30 April 2025.
- ^ Bernard Lietaer: transaction.net Community Currencies: A New Tool for the 21st Century.
- ^ Sidman, Josh (25 March 2024). "Silvio Gesell: Beyond Capitalism vs Socialism" Class #5 (Video). Henry George School of Economics. Event occurs at 44:41. Retrieved 30 April 2025.
- ^ Sidman, Josh (11 March 2024). "Silvio Gesell: Beyond Capitalism vs Socialism" Class #3 (Video). Henry George School of Economics. Event occurs at 16:32. Retrieved 30 April 2025.
- ^ Fuders, Felix (April 2023). How to Fulfill the UN Sustainability Goals: Rethinking the Role and Concept of Money in the Light of Sustainability. Cham, Switzerland: Springer Nature Switzerland AG. ISBN 978-3-031-37767-9. Retrieved 30 April 2025.
- ^ a b Steadman, Ian (11 May 2013). "Wary of Bitcoin? A guide to some other cryptocurrencies". Ars Technica. Archived from the original on 14 May 2013. Retrieved 26 May 2025.
- ^ a b Keynes, John Maynard (February 1936). "Book 6, Chapter 23: Notes on Mercantilism, The Usury Laws, Stamped Money and Theories Of Under-Consumption". The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan. ISBN 978-0-230-00476-4. Retrieved 17 April 2025 – via Freie Universität Berlin.
{{cite book}}
: ISBN / Date incompatibility (help) - ^ Anwar, Ahmed (December 2020). "From Keynes' Liquidity Preference to Gesell's Basic Interest" (PDF). Discussion Paper Series. 299. University of Edinburgh School of Economics: 29. Retrieved 26 May 2025.
- ^ Blanc, Jérôme (October 1998). "Free Money for Social Progress: Theory and Practice of Gesell's Accelerated Money". American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Inc. 57 (4). American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Inc.: 469–483. Retrieved 25 May 2025.
- ^ Sidman, Josh (17 April 2024). "Silvio Gesell: Beyond Capitalism vs Socialism" Class #8 (Video). Henry George School of Economics. Event occurs at 41:38. Retrieved 25 May 2025.
- ^ a b Sidman, Josh (10 April 2024). "Silvio Gesell: Beyond Capitalism vs Socialism" Class #7 (Video). Henry George School of Economics. Event occurs at 35:22. Retrieved 30 April 2025.
- ^ a b "Depreciating currencies: The money-go-round". The Economist. 22 January 2009. Archived from the original on 9 February 2023. Retrieved 8 February 2018.
- ^ Läufer, Nikolaus (31 December 2006). "Natural Economic Order Theories or Freiwirtschaftslehre (Silvio Gesell)" (in German). University of Konstanz. Archived from the original on 20 November 2012. Retrieved 3 April 2014.
- ^ Altvater, Elmar. "Eine andere Welt mit welchem Geld?" [Another world with what money?] (PDF). Freie Universität Berlin. Retrieved 27 April 2025.
- ^ Onken, Werner (31 December 2004). "Für eine andere Welt mit einem anderen Geld – Sind die Geldreformer wirklich Antisemiten?" [For another world with another money: Are the money reformers really anti-Semites?]. Freie Universität Berlin. Retrieved 27 April 2025.
- ^ a b Svensson, Roger (April 2013). Renovatio Monetae: Bracteates and Coinage Policies in Medieval Europe. Stockholm, Sweden: DeckersSnoeck, Belgium. ISBN 978-1-907427-29-9.
- ^ a b c Lietaer, Bernard A. (2000). Mysterium Geld. Emotionale Bedeutung und Wirkungsweise eines Tabus [Mystery of Money]. Riemann Verlag. ISBN 978-3570500095.
- ^ Décobert, C. (1991), Le mendiant et le combattant, L’institution de l’islam, Paris: Éditions du Seuil, pp. 238–240.
- ^ Medani Ahmed and Sebastian Gianci, Zakat, Encyclopedia of Taxation and Tax Policy, p. 479, quote: "As one of the Islam's five pillars, zakat becomes an obligation due when, over a lunar year, one controls a combination of income and wealth equal to or above Nisaab."
- ^ Sarwar, Muhammad (2015). al-Kafi Volume 1 of 8 (2nd ed.). New York: The Islamic Seminary Inc. p. 345. ISBN 978-0-9914308-6-4.
- ^ a b Yusuf al-Qaradawi (1999), Monzer Kahf (transl.), Fiqh az-Zakat, Dar al Taqwa, London, Volume 1, ISBN 978-967-5062-766, p. xix.
- ^ Marty, Martin E. & Appleby, R. Scott (1996). Fundamentalisms and the state: remaking polities, economies, and militance. University of Chicago Press. p. 320. ISBN 978-0-226-50884-9.
- ^ Samiul Hasan (2015). Human Security and Philanthropy: Islamic Perspectives and Muslim Majority Country Practices. Springer. p. 130. ISBN 978-1493925254.
- ^ Benjes, Hermann (2003). "Das Mirakel von Guernsey" [The Miracles of Guernsey] (PDF) (sixth ed.). ISBN 3-00-000204-9. Archived from the original (PDF) on 8 December 2015. Retrieved 11 May 2025.
- ^ Gesell, Silvio (1922). Die Guernsey-Markthalle. In: Die Freiwirtschaft durch Freiland und Freigeld [The Guernsey Market Hall. The free economy through free land and free money]. Silvio Gesell: Gesammelte Werke, Gauke Verlag für Sozialökonomie. Vol. 14. Kiel, Germany.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link) - ^ a b Boyle, David (2002). The Money Changers: Currency Reform from Aristotle to E-cash. Earthscan. ISBN 978-1-85383-895-8.
- ^ a b Helleiner, Eric; Helleiner, Faculty of Arts Chair in International Political Economy Professor Eric (2003). The Making of National Money: Territorial Currencies in Historical Perspective. Cornell University Press. ISBN 978-0-8014-4049-6.
- ^ a b Catherine Célimène et Guy Deffeyes, 1995, Le Nouveau Pari monnaie-terre; voyage au pays de l'art de dissoudre le chômage et quelques autres préjugés…, janvier 1995, éditions Terre Active
- ^ Laacher Smaïn. L'État et les systèmes d'échanges locaux (SEL). Tensions et intentions à propos des notions de solidarité et d'intérêt général. In: Politix, vol. 11, n°42, Deuxième trimestre 1998. Définir l'intérêt général, sous la direction de Brigitte Gaïti, Arthur Jobert et Jérôme Valluy. pp. 123-149
- ^ a b Wolfgang Broer: Schwundgeld: Bürgermeister Michael Unterguggenberger und das Wörgler Währungsexperiment 1932/33, 2007, p. 323, ISBN 3706544725, 9783706544726.
- ^ a b Warner, Jonathan (2012). "Iowa Stamp Scrip: Economic Experimentation in Iowa Communities during the Great Depression". University of Iowa. The State Historical Society of Iowa. Retrieved 21 April 2025.
- ^ Fisher, Irving (1933). Stamp Scrip. New York. Retrieved 18 April 2025.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link) - ^ "Grundsatzprogramm der Humanwirtschaftspartei" [Basic program of the Human Economy Party]. Archived from the original on 8 December 2015.
- ^ Ferreira, Nathalie. « De la réforme du système monétaire à la monnaie sociale : l’apport théorique de P.J. Proudhon (1809-1865). » L'Actualité économique, volume 86, numéro 2, juin 2010, p. 205–225.
- ^ https://www.lanouvellerepublique.fr/actu/la-lignieres-pour-dynamiser-l-economie-locale
- ^ a b Scott Cato, Molly; Suárez, Marta (July 2012). "Stroud Pound: a Local Currency to Map, Measure and Strengthen The Local Economy" (PDF). International Journal of Community Currency Research. 16: Section D 106–115.
- ^ Hasslberger, Sepp (5 February 2013). "Bashkir farmers' local demurrage currency recognized by Supreme Court". Sepp Hasslberger. Retrieved 2 May 2025.
- ^ Money: Shaimurots in Shaimuratovo
- ^ a b Margrit Kennedy; Bernard A. Lietaer; John Rogers (5 July 2012). People Money: The Promise of Regional Currencies. UK: Triarchy Press Limited. ISBN 9781908009760.
- ^ a b Garland, Eric (16 May 2012). "The Next Money: As the Big Economies Falter, Micro-Currencies Rise". The Atlantic. Retrieved 26 May 2025.
- ^ a b Westervelt, Eric (13 July 2010). "From Stalwart To Skeptic, Germany Rethinks EU Role". NPR. National Public Radio. Retrieved 26 May 2025.
- ^ "Villeneuve. Les abeilles arrivent dans les porte-monnaie" [Villeneuve. Bees arrive in the wallets]. La Dépêche du Midi. 20 January 2010. Retrieved 26 May 2025.
- ^ ACAI Office (29 November 2009). "Pézenas: Une nouvelle monnaie locale, l'Occitan" [Pézenas: A new local currency, the Occitan]. Herault Tribune. Retrieved 26 May 2025.
- ^ a b Sahakian, Marlyne (5 October 2017). "Complementary currencies: what opportunities for sustainable consumption in times of crisis and beyond?". Sustainability: Science, Practice and Policy. 10 (1). Taylor & Francis Online: 10–11. doi:10.1080/15487733.2014.11908121. ISSN 1548-7733. Retrieved 25 May 2025.
- ^ Lietaer, Bernard (May 2003). "Complementary Currencies in Japan Today: History, Originality, and Relevance" (PDF). International Journal of Community Currency Research. 8. IJCCR.net: 14. Retrieved 23 May 2025.
- ^ Charlton Standard Catalogue of Canadian Government Paper Money, ISSN 1716-0731, 18th edition, p. 13. Charlton Press.
- ^ Studer, Tobias (1998). WIR and the Swiss National Economy. WIR Bank, Basel. p. 59.
- ^ "Reinventing the Market: Alternative Currencies and Community Development in Argentina". International Journal of Community Currency Research 2000, Volume 4. ISSN 1325-9547. Archived from the original on March 21, 2005. Retrieved July 30, 2005.
- ^ McCullagh, Declan (27 October 1999). "Cash and the 'Carry Tax'". WIRED. Retrieved 2011-12-21.
- ^ Lietaer, Bernard (2004). Kiuchi, Takashi (ed.). "The Terra TRC™ White Paper" (PDF).
- ^ Lietaer, Bernard A. (2001). The Future of Money: A new way to create wealth, work, and a wiser world. London: Century. ISBN 0-7126-9991-0.
- ^ Michael Ende's last words to the Japanese Archived 2006-10-10 at the Wayback Machine.
External links
- Full text of The Natural Economic Order
- Money reform A collection of online text related to monetary reform and interest-free money, in several languages.
- Silvio Gesell Foundation